"A tech entrepreneur turned academic
takes on the “disruption myth.” Big companies, he argues, have built software
moats against rivals.
More than a decade ago, Marc Andreessen,
the internet entrepreneur and venture capitalist, famously declared, “Software
is eating the world.”
The winners, Mr. Andreessen wrote in The Wall
Street Journal, would be mainly “entrepreneurial technology companies that are
invading and overturning established industry structures.”
His essay was a distillation of a
long-held article of faith in Silicon Valley.
Clearly, some traditional businesses
such as advertising and retailing have been upended by software-fueled
companies like Google, Facebook and Amazon, the new giants on the corporate
landscape.
But there is also a very different
software story, according to James Bessen, executive director of the Technology
& Policy Research Initiative at the Boston University School of Law.
In a new book, Mr. Bessen challenges
what he terms the “disruption myth.” He makes the case that big companies in
one industry after another have built complex software systems for managing
their sales, marketing, operations and product offerings that are essentially
moats against competitors.
This mastery of software by major
corporations, he argues, helps explain rising economic concentration,
increasing inequality and slowing innovation.
“This is a broad swath of the
economy — way beyond a handful of big tech companies in Silicon Valley,” Mr.
Bessen said. “There is an advantage to software that economists haven’t really
reckoned with yet. Software isn’t accelerating creative destruction today.
Software is suppressing it.”
Mr. Bessen brings an unusual
perspective to his economic analysis. He is a former software entrepreneur from
the personal computer era who founded an early desktop publishing software
company, which he ran for a decade. When he sold his venture to a larger
company in 1993, he made millions. It was pocket change by the standards of
today’s tech start-ups, but it meant career freedom for Mr. Bessen.
Mr. Bessen then got in touch with
his former roommate at Harvard University, Eric Maskin, who had become an
economics professor at their alma mater. Mr. Bessen explained that he had ideas
about the software industry that might be of interest to economists, Mr. Maskin
recalled. The two went on to write a research paper on why patents often worked
against innovation in software, an industry that prospered when information was
shared.
The joint study helped start Mr.
Bessen’s career as an academic. His research has focused mainly on the
economics of innovation and the broad impact of technology. The title of his
book, “The New Goliaths:
How Corporations Use Software to Dominate Industries, Kill Innovation, and
Undermine Regulation” (Yale University Press), suggests a strident critic. But
his past research has also come down on the side of technology.
In 2015, amid rising concerns that
automation was a job killer, Mr. Bessen published a paper that examined the
impact of computer automation on 317 occupations from 1980 through 2013. His
summary conclusion: “Employment grows significantly faster in occupations that
use computers more.”
Mr. Bessen himself is an
entrepreneurial outsider to the field of economics. He has forged an unorthodox
career in academia, rising to prominence gradually over the years, one intriguing
research project at a time. He has become respected in economic circles without
a Ph.D.
“Jim’s not a professionally trained
economist, so he has an original take,” said Mr. Maskin, his former college
roommate, who won a Nobel Prize in economics in 2007. “That’s
played to his advantage and to the profession’s advantage.”
Blending data analysis with
narrative case studies is the hallmark of Mr. Bessen’s research. He is a
business historian and a fluid writer. His book contains accounts of the
evolving use of software in many industries, including autos, banking,
retailing, insurance, garbage hauling, logistics and trucking.
Mr. Bessen’s observations about increasing market
concentration, rising inequality,
and slowing innovation and productivity echo
those of other researchers. Most of those studies, though, are high-level
economic research.
His focus is a more detailed look
within industries and at individual companies, seeking the underlying
technology engine behind the broad economic trends.
“He has a new, complementary
perspective on what we’re seeing,” said Chiara Criscuolo, an economist at the
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. “It gives you much more
of the mechanism for why we got to where we got.”
That mechanism is what Mr. Bessen calls “proprietary
software.” He defines it broadly as not only code but also the data that
companies collect on their customers and operations, the skills of their
workers and the organizational changes they have made to exploit the
technology.
His measure of proprietary software
does not include spending on the standard business software from companies like
Oracle, SAP and Salesforce. Instead, it is the investment that companies make
in custom software from those suppliers and others, and in their own in-house
applications. Some of the software may be freely available open-source code, he
notes, but the overall system is closed.
Mr. Bessen’s analysis is based on
government and industry data, supplemented by information on jobs and salary
estimates from Lightcast, a labor market research firm, which recently changed
its name from Emsi Burning Glass. The total investment in proprietary software
grew 74 percent to $239 billion over the decade that ended in 2019, the most
recent government statistics. The big companies use this technology to manage
complexity and gain competitive advantage, according to Mr. Bessen.
The big banks use their software and customer data to
customize credit card offerings to individuals in a way that smaller rivals
cannot. Walmart and Amazon use their proprietary software to streamline
logistics and personalize marketing. Google and Facebook use it to target ads.
Insurers use it to tailor and market health plans to
individuals.
Pharmacy benefit management
companies use it to navigate the complexity of drug reimbursement plans. And
the list goes on. Evidence of the proprietary software advantage is abundant
and convincing, in Mr. Bessen’s view.
The software-enabled winners in
industries are more productive than their smaller rivals, and they pay more —
17 percent more on average for the same jobs, Mr. Bessen estimates.
But their success, he argues, has come at too great a price.
Competition has suffered. Since the late 1990s, the chances of unseating a
dominant firm — typically, one of the top four by sales in an industry — have
declined by half.
And technology, he contends, is
spreading and being adopted across industries more slowly than in the past,
which exacerbates the trends of inequality and market concentration.
His policy answer is not to break up
dominant companies, but to nudge or force them to open up. For example, IBM,
under antitrust pressure, unbundled its software from its hardware business in
1969. That move, Mr. Bessen writes, led to a flourishing software industry.
Today’s proprietary platforms, he asserts, could be opened
through access to their software platforms or to customer data they have harvested
— a prescription that policymakers in Europe and America are considering.
Mr. Bessen points to a seemingly
unlikely protagonist: Amazon. Opening its computing infrastructure, he said,
created the cloud computing industry. “In some ways,” he said, “Amazon is a
model of what I’d like to see other firms do,” though with appropriate
regulatory oversight.
One critique of Mr. Bessen’s
analysis is that he is observing a wave of technology adoption that still has a
long way to run, and that his concerns are overstated.
“These superstar firms are very
productive,” said Robert Atkinson, president of the Information Technology and
Innovation Foundation, a policy research group. “The question is why
aren’t other companies as productive yet?” He added that they were likely to
catch up.
And seemingly entrenched companies
are not immune to truly innovative, technology-powered newcomers: Amazon
challenging Walmart in retailing, and Tesla taking on the Detroit automakers,
for example.
Both are exceptions, but ones that
partly support his argument, Mr. Bessen insists. Both have become powerhouse
corporations, he said, largely because of their prowess in designing and
exploiting complex software.
“Technology,” Mr. Bessen said, “is
playing a different role than it has in the past — less to disrupt than
entrench.””
Software moats against competitors are a good thing. A company with such moats is worth working for and worth investing in. And if such moats sometimes hinder the introduction of innovations, then state anti-monopoly workers should take care of such obstacles, if necessary, at the level of legislators.
Komentarų nėra:
Rašyti komentarą