"There is something ironic, almost
poignant, about Europe’s furious response to the Biden administration’s
flagship climate law. For the past six or seven years, European officials have
spoken regularly about how a climate-friendly economy was the future. “I am
convinced that the old growth model that is based on fossil fuels and pollution
is out of date,” Ursula von der Leyen, the European Commission president, declared in 2019.
It was time to embrace a “new growth strategy,” she said, one as much about
“cutting emissions” as “about creating jobs and boosting innovation.”
That’s exactly what the Inflation
Reduction Act is designed to do. But since President Biden signed it into law
last August, European leaders have called it a “super aggressive” protectionist
affront to global cooperation on climate change. The law invests at least $370
billion to conjure new American industries in hydrogen, solar panels and
zero-carbon aviation fuels. And one of its most important subsidies — a tax credit of up
to $7,500 for electric vehicles — can be applied only to E.V.s assembled on
this continent with mostly American-made batteries using minerals from the
United States or one of its free-trade partners.
That kind of protectionism is the
opposite of how experts have historically imagined the battle against climate
change. Even calling it a battle reflects our hope that climate change will
require a final showdown in which all of humanity clasps hands and annihilates
fossil fuel use forever. But there’s now reason to think that certain kinds of
competition — not cooperation — might be inherent to solving the climate
problem itself: that all else being equal, fighting climate change might lead
to more protectionism, more economic tension, more trade wars.
For nearly half a century, scholars
have grasped that a stable, habitable climate is a public commons — perhaps the
biggest, gnarliest, most important commons that humanity has ever had to
manage. At the same time, however, economists saw that fossil fuel consumption
— and thus carbon emissions — have strongly correlated with economic growth. So
countries in climate negotiations had to make a terrible choice: They could
“cooperate,” and work with their neighbors to lower emissions; or they could
free-ride on their neighbors’ emissions cuts to opportunistically grow their
economies.
In other words, solving climate
change was a prisoner’s dilemma, where each country had individual incentives
that worked against the world’s. Scholars, including William Nordhaus, the
Nobel-Prize-winning Yale economist, spent a tremendous amount of time trying to
finesse the free-riding problem. Outside of an international agreement, the
problem seemed intractable.
But about a decade ago, something
began to change. Rich countries grew their economies, but saw their emissions fall. China, which emits more
climate pollution than any other country, reaped enormous economic and
strategic benefits from its booming green-technology industries. And the world
began to understand that climate action was not in fact a trade-off — cutting
emissions does not mean giving up on growth.
In fact, low-carbon technologies, especially batteries and
renewables, are the future of the economy; they can generate energy more
cheaply and support human flourishing at lower cost than the fossil fuels and
combustion engines that they replace.
In 2020, the political scientists
Michaël Aklin and Matto Mildenberger showed that based
on the historical evidence, countries haven’t backed off on their climate
commitments when their neighbors have. Instead, what dictates climate policy is
political competition within countries — domestic coalitions vying for power
over society and the economy. Climate policy generates “new economic winners
and losers,” Aklin and Mildenberger wrote, and countries pass more of it only
when the winners have the upper hand.
You can see this now as America and
Europe fuss over their respective climate policies, and exactly how profits and
future growth should be divided among manufacturers, fossil-fuel companies,
workers and consumers. Meanwhile, executives, activists, lobbyists and
officials have their own ideas about how the economy should be run , and these,
too, shape the outcome.
Last year, Jonas Nahm at the Johns Hopkins
School of Advanced International Studies,observed that countries with export
and manufacturing-oriented economies, such as Germany, adopted national climate
policies before import-dependent countries did. Manufacturers and their
political allies saw the opportunity in green technology and pushed
politicians to seize it, he reasoned.
But these dynamics aren’t limited to
exporting countries. The Inflation Reduction Act will help boost manufacturing
the United States because our industries are after the same opportunity, and
politicians are hoping to create a base of popular support to drive down even
more pollution in the future.
And here’s the rub: Once every
country wants a slice of an industry, trade conflict is likely to follow.
That’s because clean energy is a growing and highly
strategic industry, and trade conflict always arises from these very
industries, Maureen Hinman, co-founder and executive chair of Silverado Policy
accelerator and a former director at the Office of the U.S. Trade Representative,
told me. Civil aviation is a growing and strategic industry, and the United
States and the European Union have been at loggerheads over Boeing and Airbus
for years. Both the United States and the European Union want a chunk of the
global aviation market.
This means that managing trade
disputes isn’t some sideshow to the real work of fighting climate change. It is
fighting climate change. Once you accept that, a few more ideas snap into
place.
First, countries like the United
States, Japan and those in the European Union need to calm down about the
existence of climate-related trade spats. They’re here. They’re not going away.
Second, officials and experts should pay close attention to
worst-case scenarios. One might be that Western companies simply never get
their act together. They devolve into infighting, and China continues to
dominate the new-energy supply chain, essentially making the entire world
dependent on a sole — and very politically fraught — supplier.
But another scenario might be that the
United States, Europe, East Asia and China each builds its own domestic
supply chain for zero-carbon technologies, and that none of these chains
achieves sufficient scale to bring down long-term costs. Officials should pay
particular attention to industries where trade competition could make climate
change worse. Hydrogen is maybe the biggest example: Although it could
potentially eliminate emissions from many industries, it’s also a leak-prone
pollutant in its own right. If Europe and the United States get into a “race to
the bottom” around hydrogen subsidies, supporting ever leakier and less
stringent supply chains in a bid to dominate the industry, then the planet will
suffer. We do not have much room for error.
Finally, we all must attend
to the one truly catastrophic possibility of this new era of climate
competition. The more that the United States and China see each other as
enemies, the more that they sever their trade ties, the closer we get to the
worst-possible outcome for humanity and the biosphere: a new world war. But if
we are careful, decarbonization can be a solvent of sorts, dissolving the
strife into a contest of mutual advantage. That will require a healthy
vigilance and not a small amount of luck.
Robinson Meyer is the founding
executive editor of Heatmap and a contributing writer at The Atlantic."
Komentarų nėra:
Rašyti komentarą